The silent tsunami
Apr 17th 2008
From The Economist print edition
Food prices are causing misery and strife around the world. Radical solutions are needed
PICTURES of hunger usually show passive eyes and swollen bellies. The harvest fails because of war or strife; the onset of crisis is sudden and localised. Its burden falls on those already at the margin.
Today's pictures are different. “This is a silent tsunami,” says Josette Sheeran of the World Food Programme, a United Nations agency. A wave of food-price inflation is moving through the world, leaving riots and shaken governments in its wake. For the first time in 30 years, food protests are erupting in many places at once. Bangladesh is in turmoil; even China is worried. Elsewhere, the food crisis of 2008 will test the assertion of Amartya Sen, an Indian economist, that famines do not happen in democracies.
Famine traditionally means mass starvation. The measures of today's crisis are misery and malnutrition. The middle classes in poor countries are giving up health care and cutting out meat so they can eat three meals a day. (comment: Concept of price elasticity of demand can be applied here. Meat are more price elastic than basic meal -- staple food such as rice. This is because: firstly, due to nature of good, staple food such as rice is indispensable as its carbohydrates provide people with energy. Secondly, there exists substitutes for meat as a protein source, such as legumes. Thirdly, Health care and meat are normally more expensive than meals -- mainly staple food like rice, thus takes a higher proportion of income. These three factors together contribute to a lower price elasticity of demand for staple food than for meat. Assuming prices for these two food types rise by the same degree, we would expect a less decrease in quantity demanded of staple food than the one of meat. The theory here goes in accordance with the reality where the people cut on the consumption of meat rather than staple food.) The middling poor, those on $2 a day, are pulling children from school and cutting back on vegetables so they can still afford rice. Those on $1 a day are cutting back on meat, vegetables and one or two meals, so they can afford one bowl. The desperate—those on 50 cents a day—face disaster.
Roughly a billion people live on $1 a day. If, on a conservative estimate, the cost of their food rises 20% (and in some places, it has risen a lot more), 100m people could be forced back to this level, the common measure of absolute poverty. In some countries, that would undo all the gains in poverty reduction they have made during the past decade of growth. Because food markets are in turmoil, civil strife is growing; and because trade and openness itself could be undermined, the food crisis of 2008 may become a challenge to globalisation.
First find $700m
Rich countries need to take the food problems as seriously as they take the credit crunch. Already bigwigs at the World Bank and the United Nations are calling for a “new deal” for food. Their clamour is justified. But getting the right kind of help is not so easy, partly because food is not a one-solution-fits-all problem and partly because some of the help needed now risks making matters worse in the long run.
The starting-point should be that rising food prices bear more heavily on some places than others. Food exporters, and countries where farmers are self-sufficient, or net sellers, benefit. Some countries—those in West Africa which import their staples, or Bangladesh, with its huge numbers of landless labourers—risk ruin and civil strife. Because of the severity there, the first step must be to mend the holes in the world's safety net. That means financing the World Food Programme properly. The WFP is the world's largest distributor of food aid and its most important barrier between hungry people and starvation. Like a $1-a-day family in a developing country, its purchasing power has been slashed by the rising cost of grain. Merely to distribute the same amount of food as last year, the WFP needs—and should get—an extra $700m.
And because the problems in many places are not like those of a traditional famine, the WFP should be allowed to broaden what it does. At the moment, it mostly buys grain and doles it out in areas where there is little or no food. That is necessary in famine-ravaged places, but it damages local markets. In most places there are no absolute shortages and the task is to lower domestic prices without doing too much harm to farmers. That is best done by distributing cash, not food—by supporting (sometimes inventing) social-protection programmes and food-for-work schemes for the poor. (Comment: If free food is to be distributed, supply increases and price drops, which harms the farmers by reducing their revenue and profit.) The agency can help here, though the main burden—tens of billions of dollars' worth—will be borne by developing-country governments and lending institutions in the West.
Such actions are palliatives. But the food crisis of 2008 has revealed market failures at every link of the food chain. Any “new deal” ought to try to address the long-term problems that are holding poor farmers back.
Then stop the distortions
In general, governments ought to liberalise markets, not intervene in them further. Food is riddled with state intervention at every turn, from subsidies to millers for cheap bread to bribes for farmers to leave land fallow. The upshot of such quotas, subsidies and controls is to dump all the imbalances that in another business might be smoothed out through small adjustments onto the one unregulated part of the food chain: the international market.
For decades, this produced low world prices and disincentives to poor farmers. Now, the opposite is happening. As a result of yet another government distortion—this time subsidies to biofuels in the rich world—prices have gone through the roof. Governments have further exaggerated the problem by imposing export quotas and trade restrictions, raising prices again. (comment: Supply and demand analysis can be used to explain the rising price of food. Subsidies to biofuels shift the supply curve of biofuel downward and as a result more biofuels are sold -- which means more food such as corn and grain is used to make the biofuels. Assuming that the total amount of food produced remains constant, less food is available to be sold for people to eat -- the supply curve of food for eating shift upward. Export quotas and trade restrictions imposed by the government further shift the supply curve upward. Given the price inelastic nature of demand curve for food for eating, this shift in supply curve will result in a big increase in food price.) In the past, the main argument for liberalising farming was that it would raise food prices and boost returns to farmers. (Comment: Some governments may impose a price ceiling as a part of their regulation of for a stable and affordable food price. If farming is liberalized and these price ceilings removed, the equilibrium price will be reached, based on demand and supply, which may be higher than the price given by the price ceiling.) Now that prices have massively overshot, the argument stands for the opposite reason: liberalisation would reduce prices, while leaving farmers with a decent living. (comments: deregulation of food price will allow more farmers switch to produce food due to profitability. As food supply increases, its price will fall, cat eris paribus.)
There is an occasional exception to the rule that governments should keep out of agriculture. They can provide basic technology: executing capital-intensive irrigation projects too large for poor individual farmers to undertake, or paying for basic science that helps produce higher-yielding seeds. (comment: this results in an outward shift of PPC as the quality of resources increases. This is desirable, at least in the short term, as people's desires are temporarily satisfied.) But be careful. Too often—as in Europe, where superstitious distrust of genetic modification is slowing take-up of the technology—governments hinder rather than help such advances. Since the way to feed the world is not to bring more land under cultivation, but to increase yields, science is crucial.
Agriculture is now in limbo. The world of cheap food has gone. With luck and good policy, there will be a new equilibrium. The transition from one to the other is proving more costly and painful than anyone had expected. But the change is desirable, and governments should be seeking to ease the pain of transition, not to stop the process itself.
Shizhi
No comments:
Post a Comment